Instability of the Rupee

 
Instability of the Rupee – Surajit Mazumdar


The
volatility exhibited by the rupee in August 2013 and the continuing uncertainty
about its future course is one unambiguous sign that the Indian economy is going
through troubled times. This is something that few would dispute.

However, the
instability of the rupee may be more than a temporary problem. It could be
instead be only one manifestation, and an important one, of the capitalist
growth and accumulation regime in India of the last two decades having run its
course. A set of mutually reinforcing rather than self-correcting imbalances
inherent in that regime have grown over time and now come to a head. Insofar as
capitalist conditions are what we are talking about, a severe crisis and even a
protracted one may be the only way balance or equilibrium can be restored until
a new basis for accumulation is found. However, what the future holds is not a
given. What will eventually result and with what speed will of course depend on
the development of the social and political consternation that already exist in
Indian society and which will assume greater intensities and take new turns and
directions as a consequence of the crisis.
 

The Signs
of Crisis

The
volatility exhibited by the Indian rupee has a definite background wherein a
combination of macroeconomic problems has been confronting the Indian economy,
none of which have emerged suddenly.



» India’s
current account deficit (CAD) has been consistently growing for a decade,
driven mainly by a sharply rising trade deficit. This trend began as soon as
Indian growth accelerated in the early years of the current century and moved
to the 8-9 per cent per annum levels. Both the trade deficit and the current
account deficits as a percentage of GDP, now at over 10 and 4.5 per cent
respectively, in the process attained magnitudes never before seen in
independent India (at the time of the 1991 foreign exchange crisis they were
both around the 3 per cent of GDP mark). Even this level of the CAD is only
because India has an exceptionally large net surplus position in invisible earnings, mainly on account of exports of software services and remittances
from Indians abroad. The invisible surplus, which cancels out a significant
part of the trade deficit, had been growing before the global crisis. However, since
then its moderating effect on the CAD has waned. Moreover, since 2008, the CAD
has also been absorbing all capital inflows and accumulation of foreign
exchange reserves has therefore ceased


»   » Inflation
has remained at high levels for seven years running and is showing no signs of
abating. Moreover, what is significant is that inflation rates in India in this
period have been higher than in the other major economies of the world,
developed as well as developing. Food prices have been at the center of Indian
inflation, having grown the most followed by fuel prices. In contrast,
manufactured product prices have increased relatively moderately.
 
     » Between
2003-04 and 2007-08, India experienced a phase of ‘investment-led’ growth, during
which investment expenditure grew rapidly and the investment to GDP ratio
increased from around 25 per cent to 33 per cent. After 2008, however, the two
overlapping categories of investment which drove this process, namely private corporate
and manufacturing investment, have completely stagnated. A similar six-year
phase of collapse of investment separated the 2003-04 to 2007-08 boom from the
one experienced in the early 1990s.
 
    » Indian
GDP growth, which appeared to have revived after the initial slowdown in
2008-09 in the immediate aftermath of the outbreak of the global crisis, has in
the last two years reflected the emergence of recessionary tendencies. The most
spectacular decline has been in industrial output growth which has collapsed
completely since the second quarter of 2011-12. Rarely has India seen such poor
industrial performance over a two year period as is now being witnessed. As a
consequence, the long-term pattern of Indian growth being narrowly based on
services and construction rather than manufacturing has been reinforced. In the
last two decades, over 73 per cent of real growth has come from services and
construction and this share became 90 per cent in 2012-13. In other words, it
is the growth of these sectors that has still held up GDP growth. However, even
in their case there are signs that all is not well.


    In
an earlier six-year phase ending in 2002-03 when both industrial and
agricultural performance turned adverse, services growth accelerated indicating
its relatively self-propelled nature. However, no similar acceleration has
taken place this time, some services like hotels and restaurants have sharply
slowed down since 2008, and overall services growth has also moderated in the
last two years. Construction, which was growing at nearly 13 per cent per annum
before 2007-08, seems to be also losing steam. The sector’s growth which was
averaging about 6.5% since 2008 has come down further to 2.8% in the first
quarter of 2013-14.
 
 Indian
capitalism’s increased integration with the global economy has been an integral
aspect of its accumulation regime of the last two decades, though it has its specificity. Global economic conditions in the run-up to the crisis of 2008
played a very important role in making and sustaining the phase of very rapid
growth that India witnessed during this period. The fast growth of exports of
both goods and services, the significant flows of remittances and burgeoning
capital inflows were very much integral to the making of that growth story.
With global conditions having turned more adverse and capitalism’s crisis
showing all indications of remaining entrenched, Indian capitalism’s room for maneuver has also become more restricted.
 
    » The
combination of macroeconomic difficulties that the Indian economy faces cannot
possibly be understood through a purely aggregation analysis since. Indeed at
that level they may also appear to be inconsistent with each other. A current
account deficit implies an excess of aggregate expenditure over income and the
consequent accumulation of foreign liabilities. Inflation too tends to suggest
a situation of expenditure exceeding the available output. However, a widening
CAD is also supposed to have a moderating effect on inflation insofar as it
absorbs part of the ‘excess demand’. If therefore demand and expenditure are
running so far ahead of output and income, why are growth and investment
floundering and why does the industrial sector have large underutilized capacity? If
sense has to be made of this paradoxical combination of phenomenon, then one
has to go beyond the aggregates and look at the class nature of the process of
economic expansion observed over the last two decades for which neo-liberalism has
provided the background, by deliberate design as well as by default.
 

The
Accumulation Regime and its Contradictions

One
of the singular features of Indian growth since the early 1990s has been its
association with the exceptional expansion of India’s private corporate sector
– the domain of the big capitalist class. At least till 2007-08, the corporate
sector grew faster than the rest of the economy, and this gap was greater in
the periods of higher growth. Till the early 1990s, the corporate sector share
in India’s NDP stayed at or below 15 per cent, but this increased to nearly a
quarter by 2007-08. In the high growth phase from 2003-04 and 2007-08 the corporate
sector grew at nearly 15 per cent per annum in real terms. In other words,
corporate growth has never in independent India been as rapid as has been the
case under neo-liberalism.


What
was also a significant aspect of this growth of the private corporate sector was
the highly concentrated nature of its distribution and in a double sense. The
entire increase of the share of the corporate sector in total income was on
account of its surplus (profit, rent and interest) component as compensation of
employees increased at the same rate as the overall economy. In other words
there was a massive redistribution in favor of surplus incomes within the
corporate sector. This is what enabled private corporate savings (retained
profits of companies), which had never really gone above 2 per cent of GDP
before 1991, to cross the 9 per cent level. In addition, while lakhs of companies
populate the private corporate sector, more than half the total of rapidly
growing profits was shared between a few hundred companies belonging to an even
smaller number of business groups or houses.


The private corporate sector of course always accounted
for a very small fraction of total employment in the economy and this picture has
not changed in the last twenty years. Formal employment in the private organized
sector in India is about 12 million, up from about 7.68 million in 1991, when
the estimated size of the labor force is about 450 million and over 750
million are in the working age group. Even this growth of private sector
employment has happened alongside a parallel shrinking of public sector
employment. There has of course been additional expansion of employment in the
private formal sector of an ‘informal’ or casual kind. Even taking this into
account, it is quite clear that the rapid growth of the corporate sector has
made no dent on the informal sector dominated employment and labor-surplus
situations of the Indian economy.  On the
other side the largest employer, the agricultural sector has found it
increasingly difficult to sustain a process of rising incomes for the
population dependent on it. The spill over from that sector has been swelling
the non-agricultural informal sector.



Depressed
agricultural incomes and a large labor-surplus situation have meant the
operation of a strong wage-depressing tendency. Testimony to this is the
complete stagnation of real wages even in India’s organized factory sector over
the last two decades. Thus, the working class and large segments of the
peasantry in India have been stuck in a low-income trap for which there is no
self-correcting tendency. Even schemes like the NREGA which came in the later
part of the neo-liberal regime have only made a marginal difference to this
situation – agricultural wages have increased a little since 2008 but only
after being frozen for more than a decade. Thus for India’s labouring
population, a income and employment crisis has existed from much before the
current crisis and through even the period of the biggest boom in Indian
capitalism’s history since independence.

Wage stagnation and
depression has in fact been a critical linchpin off the accumulation regime
under neo-liberalism. It has enabled intensified exploitation of the working
class as rapid increases in productivity have swelled the surplus and profit
share. Indeed, the squeezing of the wage share has allowed this result of
swelling profits to be achieved alongside
a rising trend in the salaries
of white collar employees with higher levels of education in the private
corporate sector. This cleavage between two categories of employees has been
replicated within the category of self-employed providers of services too (e.g.
domestic helps versus self-employed professionals). The low wage economy and
the consequent cheap availability of a range of labor-intensive services have thus
effectively raised the real incomes of those with higher salaries and incomes. In
many cases where such services are ‘produced’ on capitalist lines (e.g.
security, sanitary or courier services or restaurants), it has allowed high
incomes to be generated for some by enabling cheap and yet profitable provision
of these services domestically. By keeping prices of non-tradable services low,
low wages have also contributed to keeping the exchange rate lower than what
purchasing power parity would dictate (a dollar thus buys less in the US than
the rupees it could be converted into at the prevailing exchange rate can buy
in India). This has reduced the dollar cost of production of exportable labor-intensive
tradable services even when they involve large high salary employment as in
India’s software sector. Wage and income depression have thus in many ways
provided the foundation for sharply rising corporate profits and an enrichment
of a diverse category of high personal income earners deriving their earnings
from business and ownership of assets or as salaries and professional incomes. In
response to the latter, public sector salaries also eventually went up and more
so at the higher end of the salary range.
The increasing concentration of spending ability
implied by the trend in income-distribution has been reinforced by the
processes of
financial
liberalization and opening up. Financial liberalization widened the disparity
in access to credit even more in favor of the corporate sector and
higher-income groups even as it facilitated credit flows to newer expenditures.
Opening up also gave the Indian corporate sector access to international
capital markets and foreign capital access to the Indian economy. The other
side of this of course was the restrictions on the ability of the state to mobilize resources and to spend, a tendency moderated to the extent that
increasing inequalities generated higher revenues without higher tax rates.


The top-heavy growth of private spending ability
at the top of the Indian economy also fueled spending on goods and services as
well as assets by the private corporate sector as well as high income households.
Many components of this expenditure were consistent with and reinforced each
other and these created the conditions for the boom before 2007-08. The demand
of the rich for assets was satisfied by the acquisition of financial assets and
also real estate. The former facilitated, along with growing retained earnings,
the financing of the rapid growth of corporate investment in manufacturing. This
investment in turn, along with growing expenditure on construction as a result
of the real estate boom, and the growing consumption demand of high income
groups all also expanded the demand for manufactured products necessary for
sustaining capacity expansion in that sector. Asset price inflation (in the
stock market and real estate sectors in particular) fueled by large capital
inflows strengthened these tendencies.


While the growth of investment at breakneck speed
was manufacturing centered, the contradictions in that accumulation process were
expressed by the fact that this boom was accompanied by two other trends. The
first was a sharply rising trade deficit that was initially driven most by
rising imports of manufactured products and not so much oil and gold imports.
The second was that though manufacturing growth performance was good, services
and construction grew faster. In other words the expenditure pattern that was
being generated by the boom also had an import-intensive and services intensive
character – both of which were to in conflict with an investment or
accumulation process so heavily concentrated on manufacturing and leading to
rapid growth of capacity in that sector. In this way the boom itself set up the
conditions for an eventual collapse of private corporate and manufacturing
investment. Income-distribution trends inherent in it implied that those who
might have spent an increasing proportion of their incomes on manufactured
consumption goods with a high domestic value added component experienced an
income freeze or depression, while those who could spend more spent on goods
and services with high manufactured import content even as they simultaneously
diversified their expenditure increasingly in favor of services. The faster
growth of imports compared to exports also reflected a feature of India’s
increased integration with the global economy, namely its inability to emerge
as a competitive location for production of a sufficiently wide range of
manufactured products (which had to depend on more than simply low wages).


At the same time as the industrial sector was
experiencing a growing disequilibrium between expansion of capacity and of
demand, the agricultural sector faced a different situation. The structure of
spending ability did not lead to demand for food increasing except an
upper-income group based expansion in the case of meat, eggs and fish. However,
unlike what was the case of manufacturing, investment in land constrained
agriculture was also simultaneously constrained by that structure. The
conditions required for those with means to invest in agriculture did not exist
while those who could in the existing conditions did not have the means or the
incentive to do so. Poor agricultural performance, the agrarian crisis, and the
increasing entrenchment of speculative tendencies in the economy contributed to
the emergence of food price inflation as a way of resolving this particular
disequilibrium. Trade in food also added rather than ameliorated this
inflationary tendency.


The collapse of investment and growth
(particularly of industry) and a food price driven inflationary process were
thus the products of the accumulation regime of Indian capitalism under
neo-liberalism. The collapse of investment in turn has a reinforcing effect on
the industrial slowdown as investment is also a major source of manufacturing
demand. The previous investment collapse in the second half of the 1990s was
also accompanied by industrial slowdown. However, while the current slowdown
too has moderated the growth of imports of manufactured products, this time has
not resulted in correcting the current account imbalance. Instead the CAD has
increased dramatically with the consequence that the significance of the growth
and investment collapse and high inflation has become even more severe.


The
Current Account: Before and During the Global Crisis

India was in some senses an outlier among developing countries in the period before the global crisis. The larger pattern
in that period was of rapid net export growth of developing countries and an
explosion of what was called the process of capital flowing uphill – net
capital exports from them the Third World to advanced capitalist countries.
Most third world countries saw their current account positions improving –
reduction in deficit or a surplus – on account of fast growth of exports of
manufactured products or primary commodities. India too saw a pick-up of growth
of manufactured products and some primary products like iron ore, mainly on the
basis of growing demand from other developing countries, but its imports grew
faster. This difference was so sharp that despite the extraordinary growth of
the invisible surplus, the current account gap increased – a pattern of
movement in that phase more typical of advanced capitalist countries than among developing countries. However, the fact that invisible kept the CAD within limits was important for ensuring capital inflows into India, which were
so large that they not only covered the deficit but also led to rapid
accumulation of reserves. The rupee in fact appreciated during this period
despite the widening current and trade deficits – a US dollar was worth about
Rs. 48 in early 2003 but fell to below Rs. 40 in 2008. However, given that
India was not a major destination for export-oriented FDI, volatile and
speculative capital inflows dominated imports of capital into India.


The collapse of investment did not resolve the problem
of a growing CAD imbalance for a combination of reasons. On the one hand, since
it coincided with the onset of the global crisis, the CAD reflected the adverse
effects of the crisis on exports and invisible earnings. The heavy dependence
of the latter on demand from advanced capitalist countries, particularly the
US, made conditions more difficult. Import growth however still continued.
Partly this was on account of oil imports with spikes in oil prices at times
adding to the problems. Global economic conditions also made the global market
place more competitive intensifying the import competition faced by Indian
industry. There was an arresting of the rising trend in the manufactured
imports to GDP ratio, which saw it go up from below 5 per cent in 2003-03 to
over 10 per cent by 2008-09, but not a significant reversal. At the same time a
crucial development was that the collapse of the boom induced a shift of some
of the asset demand of high income groups towards gold, which is entirely
imported. The ultimate result of all of these was that after 2008, India’s
current account moved in the same direction as other developing countries and
its deficit did not shrink in line with the trend of the advanced capitalist
economies India was following before the crisis. With capital inflows not being
enough to more than cover this gap, a trend of depreciation of the rupee
through periodic episodes of the kind seen recently accompanying the stagnation
or even decline in foreign exchange reserves has set in since 2008.


Correction or Deepening Crisis? The Future of the
Accumulation Regime

How
the state will respond to the growing economic imbalances inherent in the
accumulation regime will of course be affected by the operation of the fundamental
class imbalances of Indian capitalism. These fundamental balances have been
reinforced by neo-liberalism which tends to circumscribe the autonomous role of
the state and privilege private capital. In times of crisis in that regime, the
immediate effect is their further fortification as the state’s dependence on
private capital to revive the fortunes of the economy tends to intensify. What
is being witnessed today in India is precisely this intensified pressure on the
state to improve the ‘state of confidence’ of foreign and domestic capital a
desperate attempt to keep the tap of capital inflows open and reviving
corporate investment  – giving rise to a
drive towards ‘austerity’ on the one hand and more neo-liberal ‘reforms’ on the
other. The desperation of the state, however, ultimately reflects the
desperation of capital to revive the accumulation process which has served it
so well.


If
economic policy making remains trapped in the logic of neo-liberalism it can do
little to correct the imbalances inherent in it. Only the active use of fiscal
policy and not minimalism can change the fundamental structure of spending
towards greater balance. Those imbalances we have seen do not also
spontaneously create a process of smooth self-correction but in fact can give
rise to a process of reinforcing them.  The
Indian rupee first appreciated despite a rising CAD while the reversal in that
trend of the rupee has not achieved the same for the current account. The
tendency for rupee depreciation in fact has acquired a self-reinforcing nature
as it simultaneously spurs inflation given India’s large dependence on oil
imports. Since per-capita oil and energy consumption in India are already among the lowest in the world, that this rise in fuel prices would curb
demand and therefore imports is unlikely. Moderation of fuel price increases by
subsidies or by reducing the heavy taxes on them are also unlikely in the face
of austerity. The possibility of rupee depreciation also means that for the
corporate sector, the scope for financing investment through external
commercial borrowing is becoming more risky at a time when domestic interest
rates are also being kept high for the same reason. This makes a revival of
corporate and industrial investment even more difficult.  Slack growth also has an adverse impact on
tax revenues which makes the severity of austerity greater.


Fiscal
austerity achieved at the cost of a sustained large CAD, high inflation and
slack growth and investment may not be sufficient to maintain the ‘confidence’
of foreign investors even as the dependence on large foreign capital inflows
will be great. Each of these problems will have a dampening effect on
expectations about the Indian economy and the Indian rupee. Acting together or
in combination, their effect can be lethal – inducing not inflows but outflows.
If they persist for some period of time then they would make India a prime
candidate for facing and triggering a currency crisis and its associated
economic turmoil. Such a currency crisis may be the form in which the crisis created from within the accumulation
regime expresses its fullest capacity for devastation. Even if the Indian
economy fortuitously avoids such an extreme eventuality, however, the crisis of
the regime itself will not be resolved by such an escape.